Econ 808 - Fall 2003 

Syllabus

- Course description and outline

Problem Sets and Exams

Problem Set 1  (due September 23)
Problem Set 2  (due October 7)
Problem Set 3  (due October 21)
Problem Set 4  (due November 4)
Problem Set 5  (due November 18)
Problem Set 6  (due at final exam)
Midterm
Final

Papers

Methodological  Issues

These 2 papers explain why macroeconomists worry so much about "microfoundations" (i.e., why it is so important to explain macroeconomic aggregates
in terms of the underlying preferences and technologies of individual agents).

Lucas (1976),  "Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique", Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy
Sargent (1980),  "Rational Expectations and the Reconstruction of Macroeconomics", Quarterly Review (Minneapolis Fed)

The next paper discusses the tension between positive and normative approaches to macroeconomics. It points to a potential logical inconsistency in the Lucas Critique.
It points out that the Lucas Critique may be unimportant from a purely positive perspective in which government policy is made endogenous.

Sargent (1984),  "Autoregressions, Expectations, and Advice"American Economic Review

Review of Dynamic Optimization

The first paper provides a relatively intuitive exposition of continuous-time dynamic optimization.  Stokey's covers the same material but is somewhat more rigorous.

Obstfeld (1992), "Dynamic Optimization in Continuous-Time: A Guide for the Perplexed",  Unpublished notes
Stokey (2003),  "Introduction to Optimal Control",  Unpublished notes

Growth Theory

The first 2 papers ignited the endogenous growth revolution. Romer's model is based on learning-by-doing externalities. Lucas' model is based on human capital. The third
paper is a nice survey of endogenous growth theory.

Romer (1986),  "Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth", Journal of Political Economy
Lucas (1988),  "The Mechanics of Economic Development", Journal of Monetary Economics
Romer (1994),  "The Origins of Endogenous Growth"Journal of Economic Perspectives

The next paper argues that the original Solow model fits the data well if it is extended to include human capital as a third factor of production

Mankiw, Romer, and Weil (1992),  "A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth"Quarterly Journal of Economics

The next paper points out that if the Solow model is true (with identical technologies across countries) there should be HUGE incentives for capital to flow into poor countries

Lucas (1990),  "Why Doesn't Capital Flow from Rich to Poor Countries?", American Economic Review

The next three papers argue that it is impossible to explain the cross-sectional distribution of income levels unless you assume that technology levels differ.
Parente and Prescott offer political economy-based  models to explain why technology does not diffuse across countries.

Prescott (1998),  "Needed: A Theory of Total Factor Productivity", International Economic Review
Parente & Prescott (1994),  "Barriers to Technology Adoption and Development"Journal of Political Economy
Parente & Prescott (1999),  "Monopoly Rights: A Barrier to Riches"American Economic Review

Real Business Cycles

The first 3 papers provide general overviews of the RBC approach. Prescott's Minneapolis Fed piece is probably the most influential paper in the literature. It makes the
(in)famous claim that technology shocks account for 70% of business cycles. Summers' critique anticipated much of the next decade's refinements. Plosser provides a nice survey.

Prescott (1986), "Theory Ahead of Business Cycle Measurement", Quarterly Review (Minneapolis Fed)
Summers (1986), "Some Skeptical Observations on Real Business Cycle Theory", Quarterly Review (Minneapolis Fed)
Prescott (1986),  "Response to a Skeptic", Quarterly Review (Minneapolis Fed)
Plosser (1989),  "Understanding Real Business Cycles"Journal of Economic Perspectives

The early RBC models did not fit labor market data. They did not generate enough variability in labor hours and they predicted a counterfactually high correlation between hours
and average productivity. The Hansen-Wright paper shows that the volatility problem can be fixed if there is a fixed cost to going to work. The Christiano-Eichenbaum paper
shows that the hours-productivity correlation problem can be mitigated if government spending shocks are added to the model. These produce a negative correlation between hours
and productivity. Finally, McGrattan extends the Christiano-Eichenbaum paper by introducing distortionary taxation. With distortionary taxes government spending shocks
(and their implied taxes)  produce substitution effects in labor supply.  This substantially improves the performance of the model.

Hansen & Wright (1992), "The Labor Market in Real Business Cycle Theory"Quarterly Review (Minneapolis Fed)
Christiano & Eichenbaum (1992), "Current Real Business Cycle Theories and Aggregate Labor Market Fluctuations", AER
McGrattan (1994), "A Progress Report on Business Cycle Models", Quarterly Review (Minneapolis Fed)

The early RBC models focused on a closed economy. The next paper is an influential two-country extension of the basic RBC model. It shows that standard open economy RBC
models generate cross-country consumption correlations that are too high and output correlations that are too lows. The model also generates an excessively volatile trade balance.

Backus, Kehoe & Kydland (1992), "International Real Business Cycles"Journal of Political Economy

Recently, the RBC approach has come under attack on a number of fronts. The following 2 papers are among the most influential.  The Burnside et al piece discusses various
potential biases in Solow residuals as measures of technology shocks. The Cogley-Nason paper argues that RBC models contain virtually no endogenous propagation.

Burnside, Eichenbaum & Rebelo (1993), "Labor Hoarding and the Business Cycle"Journal of Political Economy
Cogley & Nason (1995),  "Output Dynamics in Real Business Cycle Models"American Economic Review

Finally, Lucas provides some perspective on the importance of understanding business cycles.  He summarizes a research program that he initiated in 1987 which attempts to
calculate the welfare costs of business cycles.  His original estimate suggested that business cycles have very small wefare effects - orders of magnitude smaller than the welfare
effects of growth.  The following article argues that this original estimate is robust to a number of reasonable modifications.

Lucas (2003),  "Macroeconomic Priorities", American Economic Review

Unemployment

The next paper surverys the influential Mortensen-Pissarides search model of equilibrium unemployment. It points to several empirical shortcomings of the model, and argues that
the source of the problem lies in the Nash Bargaining wage setting assumption.

Shimer (2003),  "The Cyclical Behavior of Equilibrium Unemployment and Vacancies: Evidence and Theory", working paper

Time Consistency

Like the Lucas Critique, the time consistency problem is a recurring theme running through all of macroeconomics. Kydland and Prescott (1977) is the seminal paper, and is still worth
reading. Barro and Gordon (1983) show how reputational considerations may mitigate the time consistency problem. Stokey surveys the literature. She notes that in models of
reputation building there may be a trade-off between "observability" (ie, the accuracy with which the private sector can monitor the government's actions) and "tightness" (ie, how
closely the policy instrument is linked to the ultimate objectives of policy). Finally, Alvarez, Kehoe, and Neumeyer show that optimal monetary and fiscal policies are time
consistent if and only if the Friedman Rule is optimal under commitment.

Kydland & Prescott (1977), "Rules Rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans", Journal of Polit. Economy
Barro&Gordon (1983), "Rules, Discretion, and Reputation in a Model of Monetary Policy", Journal of Monetary Economics
Stokey (2002),  " `Rules vs Discretion' After Twenty-Five Years"NBER Macroeconomics Annual
Alvarez, Kehoe & Neumeyer (2003),  "The Time Consistency of Monetary and Fiscal Policies",  working paper

Fiscal Policy

The last paper reconciles Barro's (1979) tax-smoothing model with Lucas and Stokey's (1983) model.  Based on Permanent-Income logic, Barro predicted that debt and taxes should
follow random walks.  Lucas and Stokey's model predicts that tax rates should reflect the serial correlation structure of government expenditures.  The key difference between these
models is that Barro assumes only state non-contingent debt, whereas Stokey and Lucas assume effectively complete markets. By ruling out state-contingent debt in Lucas and
Stokey's model, Aiyagari et al show that Ramsey taxes contain a near unit root, closely resembling the predictions of Barro's model. However, to obtain this result, exogenous
restrictions on government asset holdings must be imposed.

Aiyagari, Marcet, Sargent & Seppala (2002), "Optimal Taxation without State-Contingent Debt", Journal of Polit. Economy